1. Inequality was greater in ancient states than it is today.
Although it is difficult to make precise quantitative comparisons, most scholars agree that the level of inequality in wealth and power was much greater in premodern states than it is today. The best study of inequality through history is still Gerhard Lenski's book, Power and Privilege (1966). Lenski shows that the level of inequality varied greatly through prehistory and history (see the chart above). He proposes a theory that the level of inequality is determined by two major factors: the size of the available surplus (determined by resources, technology, and social organization), and the level of concentration of power. The powerful kings of ancient states ruled over societies with high levels of inequality. The diagram is from Collins (1988, p.156), and a nice brief discussion of Lenski's theory is found in Collins (2004).In the diagram, the highest levels of inequality (and concentration of power) came in what Lenski calls agrarian societies: these are ancient states plus more recent states prior to the Industrial Revolution. In modern times, the overall level of inequality has dropped, and that decline actually started in Roman times. Since the Roman Empire, the amount of economic surplus has risen greatly, but inequality has declined, largely because of the rise of more democratic governments. (This diagram only shows the broad outlines of history, and it is not meant to be accurate on a detailed scale, such as for the recent past).
2. Ancient states had two social classes -- elite and commoner.
Although there was much variation in the expression of inequality and patterns of social stratification among ancient states, one generalization stands out: most of these societies were divided into two social classes. (see my prior post on whether ancient cities had a middle class or not).Sometimes there was mobility between classes, and sometimes class boundaries were fixed by law and custom. The caste system of India was a particularly closed system of stratification, whereas mobility was easier in Roman society. For more information see Trigger (2003) or Sjoberg (1960).3. Severe inequality was regarded as the normal condition of the world.
Medieval peasants paying their taxes |
In the words of Bruce Trigger, “inequality [in early states] was
regarded as a normal condition and injustice as a personal misfortune or even
as an individual’s just deserts rather than as a social evil.” (p.142). And, “The general
pervasiveness of inequality ensured that its legitimacy went unquestioned.”
(142). The medieval peasants in the above woodcut (from 1488) may not have been happy about paying taxes to their lord, but they rarely questioned the legitimacy of his position. For more discussion of this, see M.G. Smith (1966) or works by Charles Tilly (1998, 2001). Tilly has developed (in my opinion) the best general theory for how inequality works in society. Most of his examples are from modern society, but his theory applies to the ancient world as well.
I don't have any grand conclusion to offer about ancient inequality. It is important not to draw simplistic implications from this kind of information. For example, the fact that inequality today is lower than it was in ancient Egypt or Rome does not mean that we should diminish the importance of rising inequality. In modern society, high levels of inequality generate many social (and moral) problems (Wilkinson and Pickett 2009). A better knowledge about how inequality worked in the past, however, can help us understand modern inequality, and may even suggest some possible solutions
References
Collins, Randall
1988 Theoretical Sociology. Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, Hew York.
2004 Lenski's Power Theory of Economic Inequality: A Central Neglected Question in Stratification Research. Sociological Theory 22(2):219-228.
Lenski, Gerhard E.
1966 Power and Privilege: A Theory of Social Stratification. Edited by New York, McGraw-Hill.
Sjoberg, Gideon
1960 The Preindustrial City: Past and Present. The Free Press, New York.
Smith, M. G.
1966 Pre-Industrial Stratification Systems. In Social Structure and Mobility in Economic Development, edited by Neil J. Smelser and Seymour M. Lipset, pp. 141-176. Aldine, Chicago.
Tilly, Charles
1998 Durable Inequality. University of California Press, Berkeley.
2001 Relational Origins of Inequality. Anthropological Theory 1(3):355-372.
Trigger, Bruce G.
2003 Understanding Early Civilizations: A Comparative Study. Cambridge University Press, New York.
1988 Theoretical Sociology. Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, Hew York.
2004 Lenski's Power Theory of Economic Inequality: A Central Neglected Question in Stratification Research. Sociological Theory 22(2):219-228.
Lenski, Gerhard E.
1966 Power and Privilege: A Theory of Social Stratification. Edited by New York, McGraw-Hill.
Sjoberg, Gideon
1960 The Preindustrial City: Past and Present. The Free Press, New York.
Smith, M. G.
1966 Pre-Industrial Stratification Systems. In Social Structure and Mobility in Economic Development, edited by Neil J. Smelser and Seymour M. Lipset, pp. 141-176. Aldine, Chicago.
Tilly, Charles
1998 Durable Inequality. University of California Press, Berkeley.
2001 Relational Origins of Inequality. Anthropological Theory 1(3):355-372.
Trigger, Bruce G.
2003 Understanding Early Civilizations: A Comparative Study. Cambridge University Press, New York.
Wilkinson, Richard G. and Kate Pickett
2009 The Spirit Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Societies Stronger. Bloomsbury Press, New York.
2009 The Spirit Level: Why Greater Equality Makes Societies Stronger. Bloomsbury Press, New York.